Tags

, , , , , , , , , , ,

When the head of state or government goes rogue, what happens next?

Consider the recent experiences of three countries where the top leader pursued an agenda far more radical than they had campaigned on, in a way that caused widespread panic. In South Korea, Yoon-Suk Yeol attempted to impose martial law, marking an attempted return to something like the country’s past military dictatorship. In the UK, Liz Truss attempted tax cuts so radical that even the business community hated them. In the US, Donald Trump is now attempting something like both: after having been blatantly caught trying to sabotage the election and encouraging a riot that sought to prevent a peaceful transfer of power, now he is not only claiming to be move toward an unconstitutional third term in office, he has also engaged in tariffs so drastic that the market’s reaction to them was even worse than to Truss’s cuts. (Trump is taking as much from the rich as much as Bernie Sanders would – just without giving any of it to the poor.)

But there is an obvious difference between the three cases: Yoon and Truss were removed from power within a few months after their drastic measures, while there is not the slightest sign of any such thing happening to Trump. And that should lead us to ask: why this difference?

Official portraits of Yoon-suk Yeol and Liz Truss. A healthy state removes leaders who do as bad a job as they did.

There is a simple core variable distinguishing the cases, and that is the members of the leader’s own party. Truss left office after a rebellion within her Conservative Party; Han Dong-hoon, the leader of Yoon’s People Power Party, proclaimed: “The president’s martial law declaration is wrong. We will stop it along with the people.”

Now compare the United States situation. Referring to the riot on 6 January 2021 that cost multiple lives, Republican Senate Leader Mitch McConnell called Trump’s reaction “a disgraceful, disgraceful dereliction of duty” and said he was “practically and morally responsible” for the event; Republican Senator Lindsey Graham proclaimed, “count me out. Enough is enough.” But none of these senators actually voted to impeach him when such a vote happened after they made their speeches. And now with Trump back, while several Republicans are voicing public concern about the Trussian tariffs, none is yet willing to work openly to oppose Trump on them or any other issue, let alone remove him from office.

A major underlying factor in this is popular support – specifically in a small but strategically concentrated minority. Yoon’s popularity was already very low when he tried to impose martial law, and he had no loyal base backing him, so his party faced few consequences for his removal. Trump, however, commanded such loyalty from his faithful that he has made Republican politicians – even the ones who loathe him, which may well be most of them – terrified to challenge him, lest he back their challengers in a primary election. The problem is that those faithful are a small minority of the American population – likely no more than a quarter – but the politicians’ fear means that that minority can impose its will on the rest of us, with disastrous consequences.

All of this is a case study in how checks and balances actually work. The US teaches its children to be proud of its divided government, with a presidential executive elected separately from two congressional legislatures. The drafters of the constitution supposedly feared tyranny so much that they created this system to ensure power did not centralize too much. The experience of recent years strongly indicates that the founders failed in that task. The UK has no such separation, and yet it was able to oust a destructive leader in a way that the US was not. A system of checks and balances means nothing if it is not used by the people with the right authority at the right time.

Why? Because ultimately the law is the people tasked to make and interpret it and enforce it – and therefore, so is the rule of law. Human beings, including political leaders like Truss and Yoon, try to do crazy stuff all the time; the idea of the rule of law is that other parts of the system limit their ability to do so. But the most important limits on the leader don’t come from the opposition party. The opposition is always an easy sell on those limits; naturally they will be inclined to get rid of a government leader engaged in wrongdoing. But they typically don’t have the power to do that; that’s what makes them the opposition. It is the party in power that is another story. In practice, in times of crisis, every national political system winds up depending a great deal on the willingness of the party in power to put the national interest over party loyalty – a willingness that the UK and Korean right-wing parties clearly showed, while the US party did not. The biggest factor isn’t the formal division of powers; it’s the behaviour within the party holding the highest power.

This is not a particularly new insight; something like it was available in ancient China. Confucian philosophers correctly held it against the Legalist school of Han Feizi. The Legalists, much like Thomas Hobbes a millennium later, rightly understood that human nature easily tends to the dark, and thought that a powerful system of laws or a powerful sovereign could keep bad human impulses in check. But Hobbes and the Legalists got that solution wrong: overreliance on laws, let alone on a single sovereign, makes things worse, because the dark tendencies of the people in charge will have far worse consequences than the dark tendencies in those they rule. Confucians knew that no formal system is enough without some virtuous behaviour on the part of those charged to enforce it – the most important virtue in the present case likely being courage, a courage conspicuously lacking from the Republicans who refuse to back up their own pronouncements.

How do you cultivate such virtuous behaviour? Before the 6 January attacks, Tim Wu had rightly pointed out the need for an unwritten constitution, “an informal and unofficial set of institutional norms upheld by federal prosecutors, military officers and state elections officials”: a shared recognition that there are some things you just don’t do, irrespective of party. That unwritten constitution clearly came into play in the UK and Korea, but has not, so far, in the US – not this time. I suspect that the major reason for this is the US’s unfortunate reliance on the written constitution, on the scriptural text rather than on institutional norms. Even back in 2003, watching the Texas redistricting conflict, I remember being struck by a Republican politician defending their gerrymandering simply on the grounds that it was legal. There was no pretence of a larger purpose, any sense of national or state interest, let alone of morality; because we can was deemed sufficient. I could not think of any example of a Canadian politician ever saying something like that. That Americans would put up with such a rationale already struck me as a sign of a very unhealthy political culture – one whose unwritten constitution is far too weak. Two decades later, Americans are paying the price for it – as is the rest of the world.